Economic Instruments of Correcting Market Failure
Instruments which over-rely on measuring economic efficiency tend to ignore many other factors, which render them insufficient in assessing economic performance vis--vis the benefits society draws from the performance. Apart from the costs which are planned for in most economic projects, another cost is paid in the environmental impact of these projects yet the environmental cost is easily overlooked by developers and the experts using the economic instruments. Gold mining can yield great profits for the economy yet when this revenue is calculated, rarely is the environmental and human costs resulting from the ecologically-disastrous mining operations. Many measures of economic performance assume that all people in an economy get equal or equitable shares of the gains of the gross domestic product. However, this is untrue in most cases and has not been achieved even in the communist nations where economies were centrally-run. A small but influential (and politically-connected) minority gets the larger percentage of the wealth. An efficient instrument aimed at correcting market failure, or eliminating some of the weaknesses of imperfect markets, must take these additional factors into account.
No one policy instrument has proved sufficient and capable of singly correcting market failure (Goulder Parry, 2008). Rather than propose one policy to correct all market shortcomings, policy-makers are confronted with the challenge of exploring a range of instruments to determine under which conditions an instrument or a combination of instruments is most appropriate (Bennear Stavins, 2006). This is because different instruments are most appropriate in particular conditions and not others. For instance, mining and manufacturing industries tend to have large impacts on the people and the environment, compared to activities such as retailing. Policies to guide the former should therefore devote more attention to social and environmental costs of the activities.
Apart from economic factors, it is important that policy makers include environmental and social factors as criteria when designing policy. Practices which bring economic benefits to one country or class while harming the environment and other people must be judged as faulty yet instruments which are over-dependent on economic efficiency may find no problem with such practices particularly when the environmental and social cost (cost of the externality) is paid by others. For instance, the cost over-fishing in the high seas by one country may not necessarily be paid by the particular country. Policy makers further need to consider not just the distribution of resources but also the distribution of benefits from the exploitation of the resources. It does not follow that having access to resources leads to benefitting from the same. This happens when markets are controlled a few powerful people who ensure that the majority has only restricted access to the markets, and the benefits.